Ensuring tickets reach real fans, not resellers
Every few years artists go on tour and try to sell fans tickets at the price they deem fair. And each time they do this, many of those under-priced tickets are intercepted by bots and brokers, costing them and their fans vast amounts of money almost certainly in the billions of dollars. Therefore we've designed SUIFT, a fairer auction for ticket purchases.




Sound too good to be true? Let’s dive in.
The ticketing industry
Famous artists are in a repeated game with their fans. When they go on tour, they seek to choose “cooperate” by charging their fans a little less than they might be willing to pay.[1] But this is surprisingly difficult to implement in practice, with some experts claiming the only solution is to effectively charge the “defect” price or to try and prevent ticket resale which has proven extremely difficult.
The problem is that, as much as an artist might like to “cooperate”, forcing them to “defect” on their fans can be worth billions. Comparably enormous resale profits go to professional brokers who are not publicly known. But they have gamed the system so thoroughly that, according to a government report, they now “represent either the majority or overwhelming majority of ticket sales”. Artists want to sell to fans, at a cooperative price, but professional brokers intercept.
Introducing SUIFT:
The Safe User Inception For Tickets
Right now tickets are typically sold by just opening the floodgates on an ostensibly first come, first serve basis. The result, as described above, is that specialized professional resellers win the majority, if not the “overwhelming majority” of the tickets intended for fans.[2] SUIFT can improve on this by running an effective auction using Flashbots’ SUAVE. SUAVE allows all parties to verify that the auction is being run fairly, while also protecting the valuable information that can otherwise allow auctions to be manipulated.[3]
While running a credible auction is an improvement, we have not yet addressed the artist’s wishes that fans only pay the cooperative face value for the tickets. To accomplish this, we can do two things:
- Refund the difference between the auction price and the “Face value price” to everyone who attends the show. This means, when a fan enters the venue the night of the show, they get refunded the difference between what they paid in auction and the intended face value. Assume the ticket’s face value is $100, but it went at auction for $300. The night of the concert, when a fan shows their ticket at the venue, they are admitted to the show AND refunded $200.[4]
- Allow artists to “amplify” the bids of those they have identified as true fans. We explain this further in the appendix, but the essential upshot is that an artist can use our SUIFT contract to select some set of fans who get their bids automatically increased at no cost to them. That is, if the artist chooses double the bid of every fan, and a fan bids $100, it will be as if they had bid $200. If the winning price is $200, the fan wins the ticket but pays only $100.
The “refund at the show” approach uniquely benefits fans based on their willingness to actually attend the show. And the “amplify the bids” approach rewards fans who might be budget constrained or, offer some additional value to the show beyond what they are willing to pay. These two together segment the market such that only true fans should ever want to hold a ticket.
The price is right, but only for true fans.
Add to this setup a “fan value”; a value some bidders are assumed to provide in addition to the amount they pay for the tickets. Artists who intentionally “underprice” their tickets may do so because there is some benefit to audience members cheering, or singing along or, as discussed earlier, engaging in some longer-term “cooperation” to which underpricing is a response. This “fan value”, assumed (initially) to accrue only to the artist, is the vector
Ticketmaster’s “Verified Fan” program can be thought of as an attempt to set a threshold fan value, such that any fan with a sufficiently high
Formally, we allow the Artist to specify augmenting bids
Thus we have fans bidding their truthful valuations for tickets, with some of those fans’ bids being increased by. Though the preceding model treats a single ticket, it can be extended to multiple tickets as in a uniform price auction. If we assume that the artist is able to identify their fans (and thus set
Fortunately, a further mechanism can be used to weaken the bargaining power of re-sellers even further: offer the partial bid rebate upon attendance of the concert. To see this consider some fan signal
We suggest a refund conditional on attendance may implement the desired separating equilibrium in which only fans bid. Recall that bidders bid
On the other hand, Fans face no cost from attending the concert (they rather benefit from it of course.) The figure below depicts the seperating equilibrium, in which Fans get a higher rebate
This contract is created by taking in a ticket address, which is the address of the contract where we’ve described the ERC1155 tokens as tickets, the ticket ID, which is the ticket “type” (changing this would allow us to run different auctions for e.g. different sections) and a ticket supply, indicating the max number of tickets that can be sold, and a charity address, which we will explain a little later on.
Please note that this code is untested and unaudited. As of the time of publishing, it is to be used for educational purposes only.
In this contract, an artist can graciously identify certain superfans to “boost” i.e. give them an additional amount of cash to boost their bid higher. This is like a fine-tunable version of Ticketmaster’s “Verified Fan” program. Rather than set a single threshold condition for which “Verified” fans get preferential access, here we can provide different “boosts” to different bidders, effectively matching their bids. The result is a more customizable was to help real fans win tickets while paying less.
Here’s where the fun begins: a bidder enters their “verbal” bid, which is an indication of what they plan to pay and at the same time sends the base value of the ticket as their “deposit.” This deposit can be lost if the bidder wins a ticket in the auction and does not pay the delta between their bid and the face value of the ticket. This is to deter bidders who have no intention of paying from participating.
The verbal bid is placed in Suave’s confidential store, which uses advanced hardware-based encryption to prevent anyone from viewing or accessing the bid. This is new technology enabling privacy from all other parties in the auction, while providing verifiable guarantees that the auction process was handled fairly. This privacy is essential for ensuring the auction cannot be gamed at the expense of the bidders.
Because we are calling an off-chain function (_sendBidToConfidentialStore(), described later below) from within the sendBid function, it will also be off-chain. This means we will need it to return a function selector and accompanying inputs to an on-chain function call to update the data.
The owner of the contract can end the auction. Once this is done, the winners are retrieved from SUAVE’s confidential store and returned.
Because you cannot yet delete from the confidential store (or at least it’s non-trivial) we will need a sorting function to sort through the winners. This leaves room for future improvement in gas efficiency.
Once winners are announced, they will need to pay for their tickets. The payment due is the delta between their bid amount and the ticket purchase amount. Again, if they don’t end up paying this, they will lose their initial deposit.
Again, we will be accessing an off-chain function (_checkIfWinner()), so we will need to return the function selector and accompanying inputs, keeping the off-chain actions off-chain and the on-chain actions on-chain.
Post the event occurance, wow do we know who attended the concert? Easy, the owner of the contract will mark them as “attended.” Ultimately you might want to automate this step of the process, by pulling in data from a ticket scanning API. However, for ease of understanding, in this example the owner manually marks each participant as “attended.”
Once a participant is marked as having attended the event they are able to collect their rebate - the delta between their bid amount and the face value of the ticket. They receive this only if they attended the concert. All auction winners who don’t attend the concert - taking up the spot that otherwise could have gone to a devoted fan - will not be able to withdraw this rebate. A future design may allow this rebate address to be changed by the attendee, to prevent smart-contract enabled rebate transfer.
In this contract, after the rebate period (which the owner of the contract will determine), the uncollected rebates will either be burned or sent to the charity contract address. This ensures that no one maliciously prevents attendees from attending the concert in order to collect their rebates.
Now, we get to the meat of the off-chain Suave-related functions: sendBidtoConfidentialStore() and getWinningBids(). These both rely on Suave’s precompiles, which are MEVM contracts implemented in native code instead of bytecode.
According to documentation, MEVM supports all Ethereum precompiles up to Dencun as well as four classes of additional precompiles:
- offchain computation that is too expensive in solidity
- calls to API methods to interact with the Confidential Data Store
- calls to suavex API Methods to interact with Domain-Specific Services
- calls to retrieve context for the confidential compute requests
Finally, this section simply describes some internal functions, getters and sorts, for supporting some of the important functions above.
Note on DDOS and Gas Efficiency: one challenge faced in this auction design was the fact that it’s difficult to send and store actual funds on SUAVE privately. Thus we chose to impose penalties for bidders who have bid and then removed the funds they bid before the auction is completed.
You can view the code in full on GitHub here.
Authored by Matt Stephenson, Xynyuan Sun and Lauren Stephanian
- The artist’s fans may “cooperate” by, for instance, being loyal during a difficult period, or by listening to a challenging album multiple times to see if it sticks. ↩︎
- For an excellent deep-dive into this industry, see Jason Koebler’s reporting. ↩︎
- See for example the recent lawsuit against Google alleging that it did not credibly run the auctions as it claimed it did. ↩︎
- Or $100 if the fan already had their bid amplified as in 2. ↩︎
- It can be thought of as the value of participating and singing along, which makes the concert better for everyone. Or, in other settings, the value of attending a conference and asking good questions, or attending a football game and yelling to influence the refs, etc. ↩︎
- Complementarity of tickets and bidder budget constraints can introduce similar problems. ↩